Back & Forth 3: Do Sanctions Work?

Remote Visualization

Our goal in launching the Economic Security and Technology Department’s Back & Forth series is to promote debate about ideas that do not get adequate attention in Washington policy circles. As a bipartisan community of scholars, our expectation is that Back & Forth will model the art of thoughtful disagreement about unexplored solutions to our biggest challenges on economic security and technology. That, in our opinion, is the crying need of democratic governance in polarized times.

— Navin Girishankar, President, Economic Security and Technology Department, CSIS

Why Sanctions Fail

Nick Kumleben, Director (Energy), Greenmantle

Over the last two decades, the U.S. government has made sanctions its primary tool of economic statecraft. The United States has become the world’s sanctions superpower due to the far-reaching impact of the dollar on the global financial system and its increasing reluctance to engage in kinetic warfare and risk U.S. lives. As a result, the United States adds thousands of entities to sanctions lists every year, imposes three times as many sanctions as any other country, and has sanctioned a historically unprecedented share of key global markets like crude oil.

Sanctions have a simple and appealing promise. Sanctions cut off the target entity from trade altogether or reduce its revenues by forcing it to accept discounts on its sales. The United States is able to engage in offensive action toward its adversaries without placing boots on the ground. Moreover, the economic cost to the United States is often tiny, as sanctions generally affect smaller, poorer countries that do not constitute a significant share of global markets or U.S. imports. The goal of a sanctions program—like any offensive action—is to change the behavior of the target, by causing it enough economic pain to force it into negotiation or surrender.

Yet all too often, the elegant logic of sanctions does not translate into real-world impact. The world’s largest sanctions program—the U.S.-led attempt to cripple Russia’s economy as a result of its invasion of Ukraine in 2022—provides a good example of why sanctions fail. The United States and its partners have sanctioned Russia’s exports, its central bank, and many entities linked to Putin’s regime. Yet Russia’s economy remains robust, and its economic strength is translating into success on the battlefield. This is the case because of weaknesses inherent in sanctions: Sanctions in global markets require multilateral enforcement, and sanctions only provide limited deterrence.

Effective use of sanctions requires multilateral buy-in, and more importantly, multilateral enforcement. Sanctioning globally traded commodities like energy and metals cannot be done unilaterally. Thus, the United States and G7, comprising Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the United Kingdom, and the United States, have attempted to sanction Russian commodities together, via explicit sanctions on some products and a price cap on Russia’s crude oil and petroleum products. This program has had only a limited impact—Russia still exports roughly as much oil as it did before the war, and its exports may rise in the coming months as members of the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) and other oil-producing nations, known as OPEC+, production caps increase. Around 80 percent of Russia’s oil exports are taking place above the price cap, traveling on shadow fleet ships and offloading to shell companies in Asia. Sanctions fail to change the economic reality that importers of Russian commodities still need the same quantity of oil, metals, and gas.

Multilateral sanctions coordination may only have been possible in an era of unchallenged U.S. leadership. Perhaps the best example of multilateral sanctions enforcement during the era of Pax Americana was the 1990s program of UN sanctions on Iraq as a result of Saddam Hussein’s invasion of Kuwait. This program reduced Iraqi oil exports to near zero and then imposed an oil-for-food program in which Iraq could export select amounts of oil in exchange for aid shipments. It worked because it had buy-in from across the United Nations, led by the United States.

Today’s world is quite different. The United States faces a meaningful challenge from another great power, China. China can ignore U.S. sanctions and actively assist sanctioned countries to continue exporting, as it does in Russia, Iran, and Venezuela. This assistance generally takes place with the assistance of third countries—for instance, Iranian oil is reflagged as Malaysian oil to get around U.S. sanctions and offload at Chinese ports, leading to the farcical situation in which Malaysia exports far more crude than it produces. Without multilateral enforcement, sanctions only cause serious economic pain when the sanctioned country is dependent upon economic relations with the country imposing sanctions, as was the case in apartheid South Africa after the congressional imposition of sanctions in 1986. And countries rarely sanction their allies and trading partners.

Moreover, sanctions have failed to deter hostile nations from acting in ways detrimental to U.S. national interest. Russia faced significant sanctions after its annexation of Crimea in 2014 yet still invaded Ukraine in 2022. Cuba remains a dictatorship 67 years after the imposition of a U.S. embargo. The failure of sanctions on Venezuela is probably the most egregious example in recent history. U.S. sanctions have failed to remove the Maduro regime from power, deepened a humanitarian crisis, and led to a mass exodus of Venezuelans to the United States and its regional partners.

Sanctions are often the policymaker’s tool of choice in the modern day, and it is easy to understand why. They are relatively easy to impose operationally, costless in terms of lives, and near costless in terms of economic damage to the United States. Yet as in markets, there are no free lunches in economic statecraft. The evidence from the past 30 years points to sanctions as a relatively limited tool, because they fail to deter bad actors and they fail without buy-in from partner countries, an especially acute problem in an era of great power competition.

Why Sanctions Work

Philip A. Luck, Director, Economics Program and Scholl Chair in International Business and Andrea Leonard Palazzi, Research Associate, Economic Security and Technology Department

Nick Kumleben’s analysis of “Why Sanctions Fail,” seen above, brings a long-debated issue to CSIS’s Back & Forth series: Do sanctions work? While scholars and policymakers have debated this for decades, Russia’s full-scale invasion of Ukraine, the prospect of a ceasefire, and the looming specter of a Taiwan contingency have reignited the discussion.

Using Russia as his primary case study, Kumleben argues that “the elegant logic of sanctions does not translate into real-world impact.” He attributes this failure to their ease of circumvention—primarily through trade with third markets like China—and their inability to deter bad actors. He rightly highlights how China and other non-sanctioning economies have helped Russia blunt the effects of coalition sanctions by acting as transshipment hubs, replenishing critical supplies, and providing alternative markets for Russian commodities, including diamond, gold, and oil. He also correctly points out that multilateral sanctions are more effective than unilateral measures.

However, his overall assessment of coalition actions against Russia, multilateral sanctions enforcement, and sanctions deterrence fails to fully account for the true impact of these measures. By underestimating both the direct and indirect influence of sanctions on state and non-state actors alike, he overlooks their full potential as a tool of geopolitical leverage.

Kumleben’s assertion that sanctions often fail to produce tangible results is based on the claim that “the goal of a sanctions program—like any offensive action—is to change the behavior of the target, by causing it enough economic pain to force it into negotiation or surrender.” But this is a narrow and incomplete understanding of sanctions. In the case of Russia, the objectives evolved from deterrence before the full-scale invasion to constraining the Russian economy, principally the degradation of the Kremlin’s ability to wage war until the present day.

By overlooking the degradation objective, Kumleben misses the larger reality of sanctions’ effectiveness. While he correctly observes that Russia’s economy has not collapsed, his analysis fails to acknowledge how sanctions have significantly weakened Russia’s war-making capacity and shielded Ukraine from greater destruction. Sanctions have deprived Russia of more than $500 billion in potential war funds and restricted its access to key industrial components, forcing it to pay exorbitant markups for crucial inputs—in some cases, more than 10 times the global market rate. Even the petroleum sector, which has been a lifeline for Putin, is showing serious signs of strain. In 2023, Gazprom reported roughly $7 billion in losses, which the company’s own internal reports attributed almost entirely to the impact of sanctions. As a result, Russia has been forced to cannibalize its own machinery for spare parts, and the quality of its military capabilities has noticeably deteriorated. Additionally, despite massive fiscal stimulus exceeding 10 percent of its GDP, Russia’s economy remains below its prewar growth trajectory, limiting its ability to sustain prolonged warfare.

He also argues that Russia’s economic resilience has translated into success on the battlefield, but this framing is misleading. First, defining “success” in a grinding war of attrition is problematic; Ukraine remains outgunned, but Russia’s military ranks are significantly depleted. Second, while Russia’s economy has not collapsed, its perceived robustness masks deep structural imbalances. In 2022, Russia’s GDP contracted by 2.1 percent, and although it has since rebounded, much of this growth stems from an artificial war economy centered on arms production. This unsustainable model, which is based on manufacturing and then rapidly destroying weapons, does not equate to long-term economic health. Furthermore, Russia has had to tap into its sovereign wealth fund at an accelerated rate, further illustrating its financial strain.

His argument on multilateral enforcement is similarly missing the bigger picture. He maintains that coordinated sanctions efforts were only possible under unchallenged U.S. leadership and that, in a multipolar world, countries like China and other third-party actors can help sanctioned economies continue trading. While it is true that Russia has rerouted large portions of its trade to emerging economies—which are gaining influence in global commerce (Figure 1)—his conclusion ignores the power of financial sanctions, the core of modern sanctions programs.

Nick Kumleben

Director (Energy), Greenmantle
Image
Phil Luck
Director, Economics Program and Scholl Chair in International Business
Remote Visualization

Though he briefly acknowledges the dominance of the dollar, his failure to fully account for the reach and resilience of financial restrictions leads him to the mistaken conclusion that multilateral enforcement is only viable under unchallenged U.S. leadership. Large-scale circumvention of financial sanctions via third markets, even those of China, is extremely hard. The United States and its like-minded partners regulate the world’s most widely used reserve and payment currencies (Figures 2 and 3) and financial networks such as the Society for Worldwide Interbank Financial Telecommunication (SWIFT), leaving little room for rerouting monetary flows.

Remote Visualization
Remote Visualization

While China’s renminbi (RMB) has gained traction as an alternative payment currency (Figure 4), its financial system remains underdeveloped compared to the existing networks, making sanctions circumvention highly costly. The same logic applies to the BRICS block—a group of five emerging economies, Brazil, Russia, India, China, and South Africa—whose alternatives are still in their infancy and lack the scale to fundamentally undermine advanced economies’ financial sanctions.

Remote Visualization

Finally, his analysis underestimates the deterrent effect of sanctions. While he highlights notable failures—such as Cuba, Crimea, and Venezuela—he largely overlooks instances where sanctions have successfully influenced behavior. This omission is unsurprising, as effective deterrence is inherently difficult to measure, leading to a key selection bias in sanctions analysis. The most effective sanctions are those that never need to be imposed because the mere threat of economic penalties influences behavior in advance. Many states and corporations adjust their actions preemptively to avoid sanctions. However, this proactive compliance is rarely captured in traditional assessments of sanctions’ effectiveness.

His assertion that sanctions have not changed Russia’s behavior focuses too narrowly on the Kremlin—just one of many intended vectors of influence. Most importantly, he falls prey to the common misconception that the primary value of sanctions lies in shaping behavior after being imposed. In reality, their greatest power lies in deterrence—creating economic and strategic barriers that prevent adversarial actions before they occur.

Throughout the war, U.S., UK, and European diplomats have engaged extensively with countries that had inadvertently become conduits for Russian sanctions evasion. While many of these nations shared the coalition’s concerns about Russia’s illegal aggression against Ukraine, their willingness to cooperate in curbing circumvention was, in part, driven by the looming threat of sanctions against their own citizens and businesses. These quiet efforts to cut off Russia’s circumvention networks have slowly but steadily increased the pressure on Russia and limited its access to critical inputs to its war machine. Though difficult to quantify, this deterrent effect is both tangible and significant, reinforcing sanctions as a critical tool of geopolitical influence.

One could concede that sanctions face increasing challenges now that rival powers are trying to develop alternative channels to mitigate U.S. dominance. However, this trend is a reaction to the effectiveness of sanctions, not proof of their failure. If sanctions were ineffective, there would be no urgent need for Russia, China, or other adversaries to build costly new workaround networks. The reality remains that sanctions impose significant economic, military, and political costs on targeted states, making them a critical instrument of modern statecraft.

Despite our disagreements with Nick Kumleben, we strongly agree on one key point: Sanctions should be used more sparingly. Their greatest power lies not only in the economic pain they inflict but also in the behaviors they preempt, as states and corporations alter their actions to avoid penalties. However, like the overuse of antibiotics, excessive reliance on sanctions risks fostering resistance, incentivizing adversaries to develop workarounds that dilute their impact. To maintain their potency, sanctions must remain a strategic instrument of deterrence—carefully targeted, and reserved for when they can be most effective, rather than a blunt tool wielded out of habit.